Markets

For decades before market restructuring, the region’s utilities operated as vertically integrated, rate-payer-funded, regulated monopolies that generated, transmitted, and distributed electricity. Dissatisfied with investments that increased consumer rates while limiting funds for needed infrastructure, the federal government and the New England states introduced a new industry framework in the late 1990s: competitive, technology-neutral wholesale markets where privately developed resources would compete with each other to provide the least-cost, reliable wholesale electricity supply. The goals of competitive wholesale electricity markets were to lower costs, encourage innovation, and shield consumers from unwise investments. (Learn about ISO New England’s responsibility for administering the region’s wholesale electricity markets.)

During this time, the New England states also began introducing clean energy incentives and emission-reduction goals, focusing first on reducing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions from the electric power industry. Emissions regulations work well with the wholesale markets by making higher-polluting power plants more expensive to operate and providing a reliable means for cleaner resources to come on line in their place.

Over the past 20 years, the market and policy approach has driven change in the direction the states have been seeking, spurring private investment in some of the most efficient, lowest-emitting power resources in the country, shifting investment costs and risks away from consumers, lowering wholesale prices, reducing carbon emissions, and enabling the transition to a system that emits even less carbon.

Markets Have Worked in Tandem with Transmission Improvements to Help Lower Energy Costs

Transmission MarketsOver the past 20 years, the ISO’s continuous study of the transmission system has helped guide cooperative regional investment that not only improves reliability but also enables the competitive markets to work as designed. Transmission system upgrades allow the ISO to dispatch the most economic resources throughout the region, allow less-efficient resources to retire, and enable the interconnection of power plants with lower emissions. Upgrades have nearly eliminated congestion costs in the New England energy market and, with the aid of low natural gas prices and other factors, have helped drive down and mitigate “uplift” payments to run specific generators to meet local reliability needs. See the chart illustrating these lower costs on the Key Stats: Transmission page.

Wholesale Electricity Prices Have Declined, But Fuel Costs Drive Price Spikes

When the wholesale markets opened to competition two decades ago, private companies invested billions of dollars in the development of natural-gas-fired power plants because they used advanced technology that made them run efficiently; were relatively inexpensive to build, site, and interconnect; and their lower carbon emissions compared to coal and oil plants helped the region meet state environmental policies. As lower-cost, highly efficient natural gas plants displaced older oil and coal plants in New England, wholesale electricity prices declined.

Natural gas is now the predominant fuel in New England, used to generate 55% of the electricity produced by the region’s power plants in 2023. As a result, the price of this single fuel sets the energy market price most of the time—so the prices of natural gas and wholesale electricity are closely linked. The high efficiency of natural-gas-fired generators and the generally low cost of nearby domestic shale gas (which emerged as a resource in 2008) are largely responsible for the significant decrease in the average annual price of New England’s wholesale electricity over the past 16 years, after prices plummeted almost 50% following the shale gas boom. Lower wholesale prices translate into lower power-supply charges for consumers.

The COVID-19 pandemic and the continuation of regional industry trends led to historically low consumer demand for grid electricity in New England in 2020, setting the stage for the lowest average wholesale market prices since the inception of the region’s competitive markets in 2003. Wholesale power prices have increased since then, driven by rising natural gas prices.

Fast Stats
  • Around 550 buyers and sellers in the wholesale electricity marketplace
  • $6.3 billion traded in wholesale electricity markets in 2023: $4.8 billion in energy markets and $1.5 billion in capacity and ancillary services markets
  • The average real-time price for wholesale power in New England in 2023 was $35.70 per megawatt-hour

Higher real-time power prices in 2013, 2014, 2018, and in 2021–2022 were largely due to winter spikes in natural gas prices. When natural gas is constrained and at a premium—or when global market forces lead to high natural gas prices—oil generation may become more economic. High prices are an expected and efficient market outcome when system conditions are tight—signaling a system need. Winter prices will continue to exhibit volatility reflective of the fuel and weather constraints that limit the ability of power resources to produce electricity during extended cold conditions.

Monthly Average Natural Gas and Wholesale Electricity Prices at the New England Hub

natural gas and wholesale electricity prices are linked

The Capacity Market Is Attracting Power Resources

Power resources compete in the Forward Capacity Market to take on a commitment to be available to meet projected demand for electricity three years out. Whereas the energy market value varies with fuel prices, the capacity market value varies with changes in amounts of electricity-producing and demand-reducing resources.

Strong competition has generally kept capacity market auction prices low for most years. The capacity market works in tandem with the energy and ancillary service markets to provide revenue that attracts and sustains power resources needed today and into the future. Over the years, the FCM has enabled participation of energy efficiency and demand response programs, as well as new resources including renewable energy facilities and natural gas plants. And it has provided an orderly process for the retirement of nearly 8,000 MW from older fossil fuel units and nuclear plants.

Annual Value of Wholesale Electricity Markets (in billions)

annual value of wholesale electricity markets

Note: Forward Capacity Market values shown are based on auctions held roughly three years before each calendar year.

Retail Electricity Rates Reflect Different Policy Choices of the Individual States

priceWholesale costs and retail rates can vary dramatically among the New England states and from year to year, mainly because wholesale and retail electricity markets are used to obtain different products. Wholesale market costs reflect the short-term market for electric energy and wholesale production capacity, whereas retail prices reflect a state’s longer-term, fixed-price contracts for energy; the recovery of the costs to pay for the transmission and distribution systems; stranded costs from legacy, vertically integrated utility investments; and various policy-driven adders, such as funding energy efficiency and solar photovoltaic incentive programs.

So while wholesale market costs have been consistent over time and across the New England states in recent years (ranging from 10.51 cents per kilowatt-hour (kWh) to 10.89 cents/kWh in 2022), retail power supply rates vary significantly across the New England states (ranging from 17.47 cents/kWh to 29.28 cents/kWh in effect on January 1, 2023), due in large part to the different laws and power procurement practices of each state and the utilities within each state. (Source: 2022 Report of the Consumer Liaison Group).

Helping the States Accelerate the Clean-Energy Transition to Fulfill their GHG Goals

Despite significantly reduced emissions from the power system, action toward meeting economywide GHG goals set by the states is just getting underway. There is a growing desire to accelerate actions needed to meet the climate goals. With deadlines looming, the states are eager for the quicker transformation of the power grid to renewables and for electrification of the broader economy.

Because large-scale renewable resources typically have higher up-front capital costs and different financing opportunities than more conventional resources, they have had difficulty competing in the wholesale markets. Therefore, the New England states are promoting, at varying levels and speed, the development of specific clean-energy resources to meet their public policy goals.

Several states have established public policies that direct electric power companies to enter into rate-payer-funded, long-term contracts for large-scale carbon-free energy that would cover most, if not all, of the resource’s costs. Long-term contracts carry risk given the rapid development and falling costs of new technologies—and this risk of stranded costs is placed back on consumers. As policymakers seek to convert the transportation and heating sectors to carbon-free electricity to fully meet climate goals, this public policy trend is expected to continue.

Pricing carbon within the competitive market structure is the simplest, easiest, and most efficient way to rapidly reduce GHG emissions in the electricity sector. Moreover, placing a realistic price on carbon would enable consumers to pay accurate, competitive prices without the risk of paying for stranded costs. However, New England state policymakers and other stakeholders responsible for putting this approach into motion have not pursued a carbon-pricing option that effectively reflects decarbonization goals, neither economywide nor in the electricity sector.

More About the Region’s Capacity Auctions

Annual auctions in the Forward Capacity Market (FCM) ensure the system has sufficient resources to meet future electricity demand. Obligations to provide capacity are determined through these auctions three years before the commitment period. Resources that clear receive monthly payments during the capacity year in exchange for their commitment to be available to meet the projected demand for electricity. That delivery period is called the capacity commitment period (CCP)—a one-year timeframe from June 1 through May 31 of the following year. As the year of need gets closer, monthly capacity auctions also take place.

Results of the Annual Forward Capacity Auctions

Auction
Commitment Period
Total Capacity Acquired (MW) New Demand Resources
(MW)1
New Generation
(MW)2
Clearing Price
($/kW-month)3
FCA 18 in 2024 for CCP 2027/2028 31,556 105 998 $3.580
FCA 17 in 2023 for CCP 2026/2027 31,370 130 619 $2.590
FCA 16 in 2022 for CCP 2025/2026 32,810 230 311 ROP: $2.591
NNE:
$2.531 & SENE: $2.639
FCA 15 in 2021 for CCP 2024/2025 34,621 170 950 ROP: $2.611
NNE:
$2.477 & SENE: $3.980
FCA 14 in 2020 for CCP 2023/2024 33,956 323 335 $2.001
FCA 13 in 2019 for CCP 2022/2023 34,839 654 8374 $3.800
FCA 12 in 2018 for CCP 2021/2022 34,828 514 174 $4.631
FCA 11 in 2017 for CCP 2020/2021 35,835 640 264 $5.297
FCA 10 in 2016 for CCP 2019/2020 35,567 371 1,459 $7.030
FCA 9 in 2015 for CCP 2018/2019 34,695 367 1,060 System-wide: $9.551
SEMA/RI:
$17.728/new & $11.080/existing
FCA 8 in 2014 for CCP 2017/2018 33,712 394 30 $15.000/new &
$7.025/existing
FCA 7 in 2013 for CCP 2016/2017 36,220 245 800 $3.150
(floor price)
NEMA/Boston: $14.999
FCA 6 in 2012 for CCP 2015/2016 36,309 313 79 $3.434
(floor price)
FCA 5 in 2011 for CCP 2014/2015 36,918 263 42 $3.209
(floor price)
FCA 4 in 2010 for CCP 2013/2014 37,501 515 144 $2.951
(floor price)
FCA 3 in 2009 for CCP 2012/2013 36,996 309 1,670 $2.951
(floor price)
FCA 2 in 2008 for CCP 2011/2012 37,283 448 1,157 $3.600
(floor price)
FCA 1 in 2008 for CCP 2010/2011 34,077 1,188 626 $4.500
(floor price)

1 Not counted as new is the demand-resource type once known as real-time emergency generation (RTEG). RTEG resources, which participated in FCAs 1 through 7, were treated as existing capacity and capped at 600 MW.

2 Some new capacity reflects increased capacity at existing resources.

3 Additional auction information, including pricing for import interfaces, is included in the Forward Capacity Auction Results file.

4 This total includes new generation acquired in both the primary auction (783 MW) and substitution auction (54 MW).

Please note:

Zones

  • In FCAs 1 through 6, Rest-of-Pool (ROP) included Massachusetts, Connecticut, New Hampshire, Vermont, and Rhode Island; Maine was a separate zone.
  • In FCAs 7 and 8, ROP included western and central Massachusetts (WCMA), Southeast Massachusetts and Rhode Island (SEMA/RI), New Hampshire, and Vermont. Connecticut, Northeast Massachusetts/Boston (NEMA/Boston), and Maine were separate zones.
  • In FCA 9, ROP included WCMA, Vermont, New Hampshire, and Maine. Connecticut, NEMA/Boston, and SEMA/RI were separate zones.
  • In FCA 10, ROP included WCMA, Connecticut, Maine, New Hampshire, and Vermont; the new Southeast New England (SENE) zone combined NEMA/Boston and SEMA/RI.
  • For FCA 11, the region was divided into three zones: Northern New England (NNE), including Vermont, New Hampshire, and Maine; SENE, including Northeastern Massachusetts, Greater Boston, and the former SEMA/RI zone; and ROP, including Connecticut and WCMA.
  • For FCAs 12 and 13, the region was divided into three zones: NNE, including Vermont, New Hampshire, and Maine; SENE, including Southeastern Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Northeastern Massachusetts, and Greater Boston; and ROP, including Connecticut and WCMA. NNE was modeled as an export-constrained zone, while SENE was modeled as an import-constrained zone.
  • For FCAs 14, 15, and 16, the region was divided into four zones: NNE, including Vermont, New Hampshire, and Maine; “Nested” Maine, a separate capacity zone within NNE; SENE, including Southeastern Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Northeastern Massachusetts, and Greater Boston; and ROP, including Connecticut and WCMA. NNE and Maine were modeled as an export-constrained zones, while SENE was modeled as an import-constrained zone.
  • FCA 17 and 18 divided the region into three zones: NNE, Maine, and ROP (Northeastern Massachusetts and Greater Boston, Southeastern Massachusetts, Western/Central Massachusetts, Connecticut, and Rhode Island). NNE and Maine were modeled as export-constrained zones.

Capacity Procurement

  • In FCAs 1 through 8, capacity was procured using a fixed systemwide Installed Capacity Requirement and fixed zonal local sourcing requirements and maximum capacity limits.
  • In FCAs 9 and 10, capacity was procured using a systemwide capacity demand curve and fixed zonal local sourcing requirements and maximum capacity limits.
  • In FCAs 11 through 18, capacity was procured using systemwide and zonal marginal reliability impact demand curves.

More information can be found on these pages of the FCM Participation Guide: About the FCM and Its Auctions and Installed Capacity Requirement.